翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Instituto Español Juan Ramón Jiménez
・ Instituto Español Vicente Cañada Blanch
・ Instituto Estetico Manila Phoenix Volley Masters
・ Institutional analysis and development framework
・ Institutional Animal Care and Use Committee
・ Institutional betrayal
・ Institutional Brokers' Estimate System
・ Institutional complementarity
・ Institutional Critique
・ Institutional cruelty
・ Institutional customers
・ Institutional damage
・ Institutional Democratic Party
・ Institutional dichotomy
・ Institutional District
Institutional economics
・ Institutional Ethnography
・ Institutional failure
・ Institutional framework
・ Institutional Group Home 33
・ Institutional Investor
・ Institutional investor
・ Institutional Investor (magazine)
・ Institutional Investor Advisory Services
・ Institutional Learning and Change Initiative
・ Institutional liberalism
・ Institutional Limited Partners Association
・ Institutional logic
・ Institutional memory
・ Institutional Missionary Baptist Conference of America


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Institutional economics : ウィキペディア英語版
Institutional economics
Institutional economics focuses on understanding the role of the evolutionary process and the role of institutions in shaping economic behaviour. Its original focus lay in Thorstein Veblen's instinct-oriented dichotomy between technology on the one side and the "ceremonial" sphere of society on the other. Its name and core elements trace back to a 1919 ''American Economic Review'' article by Walton H. Hamilton.〔Walton H. Hamilton (1919). "The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory," ''American Economic Review'', 9(1), Supplement, p (p. 309 )-318. Reprinted in R. Albelda, C. Gunn, and W. Waller (1987), ''Alternatives to Economic Orthodoxy: A Reader in Political Economy'', pp. (204- ) 12.〕〔D.R. Scott, Veblen not an Institutional Economist. The American Economic Review. Vol.23. No.2. June 1933. pp. 274-277.〕
Institutional economics emphasizes a broader study of institutions and views markets as a result of the complex interaction of these various institutions (e.g. individuals, firms, states, social norms). The earlier tradition continues today as a leading heterodox approach to economics.〔Warren J. Samuels (() 2008). "institutional economics," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics''. (Abstract. )

A significant variant is the new institutional economics from the later 20th century, which integrates later developments of neoclassical economics into the analysis. Law and economics has been a major theme since the publication of the ''Legal Foundations of Capitalism'' by John R. Commons in 1924. Since then, there is heated debate on the role of law (formal institution) on economic growth, 〔Li, Rita Yi Man and Li, Yi Lut (2013) The relationship between law and economic growth: A paradox in China Cities, Asian Social Science, Vol.9, No.9, pp.19-30, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2290481〕 Behavioral economics is another hallmark of institutional economics based on what is known about psychology and cognitive science, rather than simple assumptions of economic behavior.
Institutional economics focuses on learning, bounded rationality, and evolution (rather than assume stable preferences, rationality and equilibrium). It was a central part of American economics in the first part of the 20th century, including such famous but diverse economists as Thorstein Veblen, Wesley Mitchell, and John R. Commons.〔Malcolm,Dewey and Reese Rutherford (2008). "institutionalism, old," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition, v. 4, pp. 374-81. (Abstract. )〕 Some institutionalists see Karl Marx as belonging to the institutionalist tradition, because he described capitalism as a historically-bounded social system; other institutionalist economists disagree with Marx's definition of capitalism, instead seeing defining features such as markets, money and the private ownership of production as indeed evolving over time, but as a result of the purposive actions of individuals.
"Traditional" institutionalism () rejects the ''reduction'' of institutions to simply tastes, technology, and nature (see naturalistic fallacy). Tastes, along with expectations of the future, habits, and motivations, not only determine the nature of institutions but are limited and shaped by them. If people live and work in institutions on a regular basis, it shapes their world-views. Fundamentally, this traditional institutionalism (and its modern counterpart institutionalist political economy) emphasizes the legal foundations of an economy (see John R. Commons) and the evolutionary, habituated, and volitional processes by which institutions are erected and then changed (see John Dewey, Thorstein Veblen, and Daniel Bromley.)
The vacillations of institutions are necessarily a result of the very incentives created by such institutions, and are thus endogenous. Emphatically, traditional institutionalism is in many ways a response to the current economic orthodoxy; its reintroduction in the form of institutionalist political economy is thus an explicit challenge to neoclassical economics, since it is based on the fundamental premise that neoclassicists oppose: that economics cannot be separated from the political and social system within which it is embedded.
Some of the authors associated with this school include Robert H. Frank, Warren Samuels, Mark Tool, Geoffrey Hodgson, Daniel Bromley, Jonathan Nitzan, Shimshon Bichler, Elinor Ostrom, Anne Mayhew, John Kenneth Galbraith and Gunnar Myrdal, but even the sociologist C. Wright Mills was highly influenced by the institutionalist approach in his major studies.
==Thorstein Veblen==

Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929) wrote his first and most influential book while he was at the University of Chicago, on ''The Theory of the Leisure Class'' (1899). In it he analyzed the motivation in capitalism to conspicuously consume their riches as a way of demonstrating success. Conspicuous leisure was another focus of Veblen's critique. The concept of conspicuous consumption was in direct contradiction to the neoclassical view that capitalism was efficient.
In ''The Theory of Business Enterprise'' (1904) Veblen distinguished the motivations of industrial production for people to use things from business motivations that used, or misused, industrial infrastructure for profit, arguing that the former is often hindered because businesses pursue the latter. Output and technological advance are restricted by business practices and the creation of monopolies. Businesses protect their existing capital investments and employ excessive credit, leading to depressions and increasing military expenditure and war through business control of political power. These two books, focusing on criticism first of consumerism, and second of profiteering, did not advocate change.
Through the 1920s and after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 Thorstein Veblen's warnings of the tendency for wasteful consumption and the necessity of creating sound financial institutions seemed to ring true. Veblen remains a leading critic, which cautions against the excesses of "the American way".
Thorstein Veblen wrote in 1898 an article entitled "Why is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science"〔Veblen, Th. 1898 "Why is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science", ''The Quarterly Journal of Economics'', 12.〕 and he became the precursor of current evolutionary economics.

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Institutional economics」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.